查看原文
其他

海外之声 | 中央银行与支付新世界

郭旗 IMI财经观察 2022-04-30

导读


COVID-19大流行的危机突显出来,金融服务需要更加包容和便利才能刺激经济复苏,而央行可以发挥重要作用。一些政府已经能够利用技术迅速帮助那些受流行病影响最大的个人和小企业,使提供财政支助的效率和及时性得以提升,例如通过向电子钱包付款和直接向银行账户付款。但这种方式仍存在缺陷。并非所有受影响的人都能使用银行账户,而且支付服务的成本从整个经济上看仍不可忽视。诚然,技术有助于降低成本,但它不能解决所有问题。技术本身不足以建立一个快速、高效和成本效益高的支付系统,这些支付成本还与支付系统的基础经济以及支付服务的竞争性质有关。支付服务是一个网络效应很强的行业。一方面,网络效应可以产生更大的用户参与度、更低的成本和更好的服务的良性循环。另一方面,如果这些都导致了更大的市场支配地位,最终减少了竞争,那么用户的利益可能会受损。在这种情况下,中央银行可以作为基础设施的运营商发挥关键作用。从这个意义上说,中央银行可以通过访问其结算账户来提供公共空间,使支付服务的卖家都能在这里互动。中央银行可以帮助维护这个繁忙的平台,引导网络效应进入一个实现更多参与、更低成本和更好服务的良性循环。中央银行数字货币(CBDC)是中央银行扮演支付基础设施运营商角色的另一种方式。批发CBDC类似于现有的中央银行结算账户,零售CBDC以电子形式向普通用户提供对中央银行的债权。零售CBDC将代表着中央银行与社会关系性质的更为深远的变化。例如,在这种数字化记账方式下保护个人信息将带来新的挑战。CBDC可能会使中央银行对金融体系产生更大的影响,因此零售CBDC的整体后果将需要仔细权衡,以衡量其可能的收益和成本。

随着CBDC的可能引入,我们可能正处在中央银行与社会关系演变的另一个重要步骤的前端。数字创新使央行的公共产品比以往任何时候都更加重要,央行需要站在技术的前沿,为社会服务。


作者 | Hyun Song Shin,BIS经济顾问兼研究主管

英文原文如下:


Central banks and the new world of payments

Hyun Song Shin, Economic Adviser and Head of Research

On the occasion of the Bank’s Annual General Meeting in Basel, 30 June 2020


Introduction

This year’s Annual Economic Report has a special chapter on “central banks and payments in the digital era”. It follows in the footsteps of the chapters on cryptocurrencies and on big tech in finance in the previous two years. If you recall, those two chapters focused on what digital innovation meant for the nature of money and the payment system. There is also a strong technology theme this year, but our focus is broader. The special chapter this year highlights the central bank’s role in the payment system.  Over the centuries, the institutional arrangements underpinning money and the payment system have evolved to keep pace with the changing needs of the day. Technology has carried us a long way on this journey, but the key theme of the chapter is that technology by itself is not sufficient to put in place a fast, efficient and cost-effective payment system. The underlying economics and the nature of competition in the payment system are important too. The good news is that new technology will help central banks put the pieces together more easily. 

Before going into the details, I should put my remarks in the context of the pandemic, which, as Agustín notes, is a defining moment for the global economy.

Payments amid the pandemic

We chose the topic for the special chapter well before the pandemic, but the pandemic has served to highlight the importance of some of the main themes in the chapter. The crisis has highlighted how financial services need to be more inclusive and accessible in order to spur the recovery, and the central bank has an important role to play. 

In some respects, the pandemic has accelerated trends that were already under way. One example is the use of contactless payments at the physical point of sale, such as in shops (Graph 1, left-hand panel). Both contactless payments, and remote payments for online transactions, were rising before the pandemic, but the pandemic has given them further impetus. Also worth noting is the use of cash. Its use for transactions has fallen, but the precautionary holding of cash has gone up. This is broadly consistent with past episodes of economic uncertainty.One very important issue is the efficiency and timeliness of disbursement of government fiscal support to individuals and small businesses that have suffered most from the pandemic. As this slide shows (Graph 1, right-hand panel), governments around the world have reacted swiftly to put in place fiscal support measures, including direct transfers to households. Announced budgetary measures add up to 10% of GDP in advanced economies and 3% of GDP in emerging market economies. Funding and guarantees come on top on this, and they are of comparable magnitudes to budgetary measures.


However, actually reaching the affected people has been another matter. Some countries have been able to harness technology to reach those in need swiftly – for example, through disbursement into e-wallets and direct payments to bank accounts. But the record has been mixed.

Shortcomings in payments

One problem is that not all those affected have access to bank accounts. And in some cases, even those who do have bank accounts have to wait for paper cheques to arrive in the post. In the future, central bank digital currencies, or CBDCs, could be a means of expediting this type of payment – I’ll get to that later. All of this shines a light on the importance of the issues discussed in the special chapter.  

Another issue is the cost of payment services. For credit and debit cards, it is mostly retailers and merchants that bear the costs, through charges to the card networks and to the banks. These charges (Graph 2) are shown here in purple, from a European Commission survey. Consumers do not see these charges, but they can add up for the economy as a whole.


The economics of the payments marketplace

Technology has certainly helped to lower costs. That is the good news. But technology cannot solve everything. The costs also have to do with the underlying economics, and the nature of competition in payment services.  

Payment services are a good example of an industry with strong network effects. This means that the more other users flock to a particular platform, the more attractive it is for a new user to join that same network. Social media and messaging are good examples of network effects. As we discussed in the special chapter last year, big tech firms with existing customer bases have entered payment services by using their advantage in access to user data. Once they reach a dominant position, they can create bottlenecks for external competitors, or raise fees for retailers. In this respect, network effects might be a mixed blessing for users. On the one hand, network effects can generate a virtuous circle of greater user participation, lower costs and better services. But if all this leads to greater market dominance that eventually reduces competition, then the users may ultimately end up being worse off.  Let me explain with the example of competition between two full-service department stores, rather like these two (Graph 3, left-hand panel). You can see that one of them has become much more popular than the other one. The two department stores offer the full range of goods, but once inside you cannot access the goods sold by the other department store. This is rather like competition between two payment platforms. To use a different analogy, closed networks that exclude competitors are rather like a walled garden: it’s very nice inside at first, but once inside you’re cut off from the outside world, and you may get trapped. 


In contrast, imagine a town market that sets up on a public square – like the one on Marktplatz here in the centre of Basel, just in front of city hall (Graph 3, right-hand panel). Unlike the full-service department stores, when you are in an open market in the town square, a buyer can have access to all the sellers, without artificial barriers.  A marketplace, like the one below in Graph 4, brings together buyers and sellers (Graph 4, left-hand panel). The buyers come to the market because they expect sellers to be there, and sellers come and set up their stalls because they expect to find buyers there.  Shoppers enter, looking to buy cheese, which in turn makes the market more valuable to the sellers of cheese. The arrows indicate the mutually reinforcing nature of buyer and seller participation (Graph 4, right-hand panel). In the terminology of industrial organisation, there are strategic complementarities between buyers and sellers, where greater participation by one group brings greater participation by the other group. 


The same effect holds for the buyers and sellers of fruit and vegetables, shown on the slide (Graph 5, left-hand panel). The sellers compete on the price and quality of their produce, and so you may think that sellers are worse off when there are many sellers. Importantly, this is a market for differentiated products, and buyers of cheese are also potential customers for vegetables. If buyers come for one good, but then also buy other goods, the sellers actually benefit from having each other in the same market.


When the sellers provide differentiated products, the entry of new sellers can end up benefiting other sellers in spite of more competition. This is because they contribute to attracting more buyers. In this slide, the arrows at the top indicate the network effects between sellers.  These network effects mean that when all these buyers and sellers come to the market, they add to the bustling and vibrant nature of the market, which makes it attractive to other buyers and sellers to come. In this way, network effects generate a public good that benefits everyone. The strategic complementarities also hold between sellers, even though they compete against each other. What this means is that competition and a bustling market through better services can be made compatible.  Notice the contrast with the department stores. The important point is that the open market relies on rules and standards that preserve a competitive level playing field. The town square is a public space, where buyers and sellers can meet without artificial barriers. In return, the sellers have to stick to the standards laid down by the public authorities that allow the virtuous circle of greater participation and better services to take hold.  The analogy with the payment system is that the market stallholders are like payment service providers (PSPs) (Graph 5, right-hand panel), each offering their particular bundle of services that comes with basic payment functionality, such as e-commerce, messaging and social media. Just as the market stallholders have to stick to standards laid down by the town authorities, these payment service providers need to stick to various technical standards and data access requirements, including through open APIs, in order to allow a competitive level playing field. The key concept here is interoperability, where the services offered by payment service providers can “talk to” each other and work seamlessly for the user.

The role of central banks

In this context, the central bank can play the pivotal role as the operator of the underlying infrastructure, much as the town authorities operate the town market. It is the central bank that provides the public space through access to its settlement accounts. In that sense, the balance sheet of the central bank is a public space where the sellers of the payment services all interact. 

The central bank is well placed to play this role, as it issues money (which is, after all, the unit of account in the economy), as well as ensuring finality of payments through settlement on the central bank’s balance sheet. Like the town market, the central bank can help safeguard this bustling payments marketplace, where the network effects can be channelled towards achieving a virtuous circle of greater participation, lower costs and better services. This slide illustrates the role for the central bank as an operator of the underlying infrastructure (Graph 6, left-hand panel). As you see in the blue line, beginning in the 1980s central banks rolled out real-time gross settlement, or RTGS, systems for wholesale payments. These systems are now very wellestablished. More recently, a growing number of central banks have played a key role in the development of retail fast payment systems, shown in the red line. Fast payment systems often allow settlement directly on the central bank balance sheet, or through public utilities overseen by the central bank. As you see in the red line, the diffusion of retail fast payment systems is following the same trajectory as the adoption of RTGS systems.


Central bank digital currencies

Central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) can be seen in this broader context. CBDCs are another way in which central banks can play the role of the operator of the payment infrastructure. Wholesale CBDCs may be similar to existing central bank settlement accounts. But recent discussion has been about general purpose or retail CBDCs that give access to claims on the central bank to ordinary users, in electronic form. 

The reasons for considering retail CBDCs are numerous and vary across jurisdictions. A survey last year of 66 central banks revealed that the safety and efficiency of domestic payments are the most important motivations (Graph 7, let-hand panel). Also, many cited the decreasing use of cash and the need for financial inclusion as a motivation. 


In some respects, retail CBDCs represent an incremental step. Users already have access to cash, which is a direct claim on the central bank. However, in other respects, retail CBDCs represent a more far-reaching change in the nature of the relationship between central banks and society. For instance, no matter how the CBDC is designed, there has to be some kind of ledger that keeps track of transactions so that the central bank can honour its obligations to the rightful owner of the CBDC. In such a setting, safeguarding personal data would present new challenges. We may also expect CBDCs to have an impact on the functioning of the financial system, potentially leading to a much larger footprint of the central bank on the financial system itself. For all these reasons, the overall consequences of retail CBDCs will need to be weighed up carefully to gauge their likely benefits and costs.Judging from the reports and speeches coming from central banks, the balance of opinion seems to be leaning more favourably towards CBDCs. Both wholesale and retail CBDCs have featured in a more positive light since late 2019, as shown here in the graph (Graph 7, right-hand panel). The number of central bank reports and speeches on retail CBDCs have generally turned more positive towards them, as indicated here by the blue bars going up relative to the red bars. At many central banks, there is work under way on the design and use cases for CBDCs. The BIS is supporting these discussions through the committees it hosts, through economic research and through the activities of the new BIS Innovation Hub.

Conclusion

If we look at the long arc of history, the social convention of money has undergone several key institutional changes. With the possible introduction of CBDCs, we may be at the cusp of another important step in the evolution of the relationship of the central bank with society. 

Digital innovation has made central bank public goods more important than ever, and central banks need to be at the cutting edge of technology to serve society.  

We may expect these efforts to make our payment systems more efficient, faster and more widely accessible for the new, digital world.


编译  郭旗

编辑  李锦璇

来源  BIS

审校  金天、蒋旭

监制  董熙君、安然、魏唯


点击查看近期热文

海外之声|保存经济实力:金融与新冠危机

海外之声 | 全球银行业“大而不倒”改革的启示

海外之声 | 新冠疫情背景下的货币政策

海外之声 | 新冠疫情危机下的货币政策

海外之声 | 后疫情时代的欧盟银行监管

欢迎加入群聊

为了增进与粉丝们的互动,IMI财经观察建立了微信交流群,欢迎大家参与。


入群方法:加群主为微信好友(微信号:imi605),添加时备注个人姓名(实名认证)、单位、职务等信息,经群主审核后,即可被拉进群。


欢迎读者朋友多多留言与我们交流互动,留言可换奖品:每月累积留言点赞数最多的读者将得到我们寄送的最新研究成果一份。

关于我们


中国人民大学国际货币研究所(IMI)成立于2009年12月20日,是专注于货币金融理论、政策与战略研究的非营利性学术研究机构和新型专业智库。研究所聘请了来自国内外科研院所、政府部门或金融机构的90余位著名专家学者担任顾问委员、学术委员和国际委员,80余位中青年专家担任研究员。

研究所长期聚焦国际金融、货币银行、宏观经济、金融监管、金融科技、地方金融等领域,定期举办国际货币论坛、货币金融(青年)圆桌会议、大金融思想沙龙、麦金农大讲坛、陶湘国际金融讲堂、IMF经济展望报告发布会、金融科技公开课等高层次系列论坛或讲座,形成了《人民币国际化报告》《天府金融指数报告》《金融机构国际化报告》《宏观经济月度分析报告》等一大批具有重要理论和政策影响力的学术成果。

2018年,研究所荣获中国人民大学优秀院属研究机构奖,在182家参评机构中排名第一;在《智库大数据报告(2018)》中获评A等级,在参评的1065个中国智库中排名前5%。2019年,入选智库头条号指数(前50名),成为第一象限28家智库之一。

国际货币网:http://www.imi.ruc.edu.cn


微信号:IMI财经观察

(点击识别下方二维码关注我们)

理事单位申请、

学术研究和会议合作

联系方式:  

010-62516755 

imi@ruc.edu.cn

只分享最有价值的财经视点

We only share the most valuable financial insights.

您可能也对以下帖子感兴趣

文章有问题?点此查看未经处理的缓存