海外之声丨数字化颠覆:监管的作用
导读
数字技术快速发展,给金融部门带来机遇的同时,也不乏风险。尽管数字技术提升了金融服务的效率,增强市场竞争,让更多人享受到金融服务的便利,但是随着越来越多新科技、新产品和以大型科技公司为主的金融服务供应商进入市场,影响市场完整性和金融稳定的风险也随之而来。
大型科技公司凭借着独特的经营模式,并利用技术和网络外部性优势,在金融行业不断地做大做强。但是,尽管它们的加入提高了金融行业的工作效率,却给金融稳定带来了风险。
首先,如果这些科技公司在敏感性金融服务方面表现不佳,则会引发过度负债,操作中断,流动性错配和非法交易等问题,使金融系统不堪重负。其次,受监管的金融机构频繁地从科技公司获取技术支持,会增加其对第三方的依赖,同时也会引发运营漏洞。再者,科技公司发布的稳定币有可能取代法定货币成为主要的支付工具,从而破坏支付系统的完整性和货币主权。最后,依靠网络外部性优势,一些大型的科技公司会发展成为金融服务行业的垄断者,破坏金融稳定。
就监管措施来看,由于科技公司给金融部门带来的风险主要源自于其在金融领域和非金融领域的同步运作,以往基于特定金融服务的监管规则难免显得捉襟见肘,于是,许多地区开始对此进行修改,有一些地区已经引入了基于市场主体的监管规则来打击市场垄断行为。
但是,目前尚未有已经成形的监管规则和标准,用于管控此类风险。也许,对金融控股公司的监管体制进行反思能给我们带来一些启示。这些监管体制主要是保护金融控股公司的安全稳定运作,使其免受母公司其他非金融部门所引发的风险的冲击,进而保护金融系统的稳定。但是,这些监管体制离发展成为基于市场主体的监管体制还有一定的距离,不能解决所有相关风险。需要指出的是,若只关注于大型科技公司的金融部门,无法更好地管控其运营风险,数据滥用和市场滥用等行为。另外,支付服务也应该成为监管体制中重点关注的领域。
作者 | Fernando Restoy,国际清算银行金融稳定研究所所长
英文原文如下:
The digital disruption: The role of regulation
Fernando Restoy1
Chair, Financial Stability Institute, Bank for International Settlements
Virtual conference by the Asia School of Business (ASB) and the Bank for International
Settlements (BIS): “Digital disruption and inclusion: challenges and opportunities”
28 January 2022
Introduction
Presentations before mine have already covered much ground on the implications of the ongoing technological disruption, including its impact on financial inclusion and resilience.
Overall, the already vast literature on the topic and, certainly, the presentations at this conference stress the complex combination of risk and opportunities that digital technologies bring to the financial sector. Indeed, it is remarkable how digitisation is helping to enlarge the opportunity set of consumers and investors, increase efficiency and competition in the provision of financial services, and, importantly, make those services available to larger segments of the population. The significant acceleration of the financial inclusion indicators in the last few years in countries like India and China – where digital payments have skyrocketed – is just one illustration of the power technology has to make the financial system more able to serve the public interest.
Yet the disruption created by new technologies, the new products and the new providers of financial services – particularly big tech companies – also poses relevant risks for the achievement of key social objectives such as market integrity, consumer protection and financial stability. Those are precisely the objectives that justify public intervention when markets fail to deliver them on their own.
The establishment of rules and constraints on market activity, such as that performed by new tech players in the market of financial services, is the most relevant policy tool to address negative market externalities. That regulatory action should be subject to the principle of good regulation under which public intervention should be minimised to what is essential to preserve social objectives. Yet regulation occasionally needs to face relevant trade-offs, as public actions aiming at containing risks for adequate market functioning may limit private tech firms’ ability to deliver services that could otherwise be socially valuable, for instance as a result of their positive impact on financial inclusion.
In that context, it is important to bear in mind that regulation is not the only form of policy intervention that can help correct market failures. At times, the direct provision of services by government-owned companies may contribute to socially desirable options. In the area of digital payments, for instance, experience in countries like India3 shows how public infrastructures may help society to embrace the benefits of technology and facilitate financial inclusion while avoiding some of the risks posed by excessive reliance on large private providers. In particular, putting in place public infrastructures such as India’s Unified Payments Interface (UPI) seems to substitute, at least to some extent, for a more forceful policy intervention to address big tech risks related to anti-competitive practices, walled garden ecosystems and hoarding user data.
The introduction of central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) is another example of how well designed public facilities can help optimise the net benefits of digital payment platforms for society as a whole.
Sound policy strategies aiming at facilitating an orderly adoption of new technologies in the financial sector should therefore incorporate a good combination of regulation and the provision of public infrastructure. While other presentations have focused on the latter, let me share with you a few reflections on how the regulatory framework needs to be adapted to preserve a key social goal: financial stability. For more concreteness I’ll focus my remarks on how risks posed by big techs could be addressed by adequate rules constraining their practices and modus operandi.Big techs and financial stability
As is now well documented, the expansion of big techs leverages on their unique business models based on technological and, especially, data superiority, which allows them to benefit from network externalities.
Big tech services have brought efficiency to the financial industry. Moreover, by offering innovative products they have eroded the historical dominant position of commercial banks in in some market segments – notably payments, for which a banking licence is not required. Furthermore, in some jurisdictions they have been able to make payment facilities and external funding available to firms and individuals who did not previously have access to banking services. Yet the financial activity of big techs does pose some risks for the preservation of financial stability which may not always be fully captured by the current regulatory framework.
Those risks stem from at least four different sources.
First, from the direct provision to the public of a suite of sensitive financial services such as payments, credit, wealth management and, sometimes, deposit-taking. Unsound performance of those activities could contribute to potentially systemic stress due to excessive indebtedness, operational discontinuities and liquidity mismatches and also to facilitate illegal activities. The parallel performance of several of those financial activities alongside the provision of other non-financial services within the same group could exacerbate operational risks and complicate their supervision by the competent authorities.
Second, from the frequent provision of relevant technological services to regulated financial institutions (such as cloud computing services) that lead to large third-party dependencies and important operational vulnerabilities. Recent outages in the technological services provided by big techs illustrate the potential significance of those risks.
Third, by the issuance of new means of payments – such as so-called stablecoins. Given the complementarity of those new payment instruments with other services offered by big tech platforms to a large number of users, they have the potential to replace fiat currency as a predominant settlement instrument, thereby challenging the integrity of the payment system, consumer protection and, possibly, monetary sovereignty.
And, finally, from the potential to generate significant concentration dynamics in the provision of key financial services. Network externalities that characterise big tech business models can easily lead to a continued increase in their size and business diversification, at the cost of damaging competition in a quickly increasing number of related market segments. Notice that concentration threatens not only market contestability but also financial stability as it amplifies the dependence of financial system participants on the services provided by a few large players.The current regulatory approaches
So far, authorities are following a piecemeal approach aiming at inserting specific rules in the current regulatory framework in order to contain some of the risks I mentioned before.
In particular, the provision of financial services (payments, wealth management, credit underwriting) other than banking or insurance are regulated through an activity-based approach. Big tech subsidiaries that perform specific regulated activities are subject to the corresponding sectoral requirements that typically address consumer protection, AML/CFT and sometimes operational resilience.
In some jurisdictions, authorities are now considering the introduction of a specific regulatory and supervisory framework for large providers of technological services to regulated institutions. That regime will affect, in particular, those subsidiaries of big techs that provide services to a large number of financial institutions, such as cloud computing.
However, many of the risks that big techs’ activity generates for the adequate functioning of financial markets stem from the combination of both financial and non-financial activities that they perform. Their ample array of services is typically anchored on shared systems across subsidiaries and an extensive use of all available data from clients obtained throughout all the activities performed by the group. Risks posed by such interdependencies can hardly be fully addressed by pure activity based regulation.
This is certainly the case of the prevention of excessive market concentration. In the EU, the European Commission has put forward a proposal for a Digital Markets Act (DMA) which establishes a series of specific requirements which must be satisfied by big tech platforms (“gatekeepers” in the DMA terminology), aimed at preventing (and not only prosecuting ex post) anti-competitive practices that could lead to the abuse of market dominance. Special rules on data use, data protection and data-sharing obligations with end users and business users are a key component of the proposed DMA. A similar entity-based approach is already being enforced in China following the rules established by the market regulator (SAMAR), and is the one considered in different legislative initiatives which are currently under discussion in the US Congress.
Moreover, we have recently seen some initiatives for the development of specific regulation of entities performing services related to stablecoins. In particular, a report by the US president’s commission composed of the Treasury and main regulatory agencies has proposed a bold legislative reform that would require issuers of stablecoins to become insured depositary institutions and establish concrete rules and a supervisory regime for entities providing associated payment services (like custodial wallet providers). Moreover, the report proposes limiting the affiliation of those entities with commercial companies. If those proposals are finally endorsed by the US Congress, the scope for big techs to promote and sponsor stablecoins would be seriously constrained.
In sum, current developments aim at revising the current activity-based regulation and add a few specific entity-based rules (particularly in the area of competition) to deal with some of the risks posed by big techs. So far, however, there is no ambitious attempt to consider a more comprehensive approach that could consistently address the risks posed in different policy domains by the combination of activities that big techs perform as implied by their unique business model.Can we do it better?
The closest reference is probably that of financial conglomerates. Following the publication of the report by the Joint Forum in 2012, jurisdictions established rules and supervisory practices to strengthen the prudential regime of entities which are active in more than one regulated financial sector (ie banking, insurance and securities markets).
One specific type of conglomerate rules are licensing frameworks for financial holding companies (FHCs). FHCs are typically large non-financial companies that hold controlling stakes in two or more financial firms that offer regulated financial services across sectoral boundaries and exceed minimum size thresholds. The FHC and the financial institutions it controls make up a financial holding group. The non-financial activities performed by this group are limited to maximum thresholds.
In China, the People’s Bank of China requires companies that control two or more different types of financial companies, including big techs such as Ant and Tencent, to apply for an FHC licence.
The Chinese FHC regulatory regime establishes requirements for the parent FHC in terms of minimum profitability, financial capacity and owners’ fit and proper conditions. It also promotes sufficiently simple corporate structures and imposes specific governance procedures including the centralised management of all relevant financial risks across the group. The regime entails the fulfilment of consolidated capital requirements at the group level and includes constraints on related party transactions and cross-subsidiary interactions.
A key objective of the FHC regime is to guard against systemic risk by protecting the safety and soundness of the financial holding group from risks arising from the non-financial activities performed by other parts of the wider group to which it belongs. It also helps address contagion of risks across financial subsidiaries and minimises the potential for regulatory arbitrage across the different types of sectoral rules that apply to the regulated subsidiaries. Importantly, that regime facilitates consistent supervision of all financial risks, including those related to solvency, operational resilience and market conduct.
Certainly, the FHC regime goes a long way towards satisfying the quest for a comprehensive entity-based regime for big techs which are active in the market for financial services. That regime may, however, fall short of addressing all relevant risks.
As we have discussed before, challenges posed by big techs for the preservation of financial stability, or more generally, adequate market functioning are associated with the combined provision of different types of financial and non-financial services as part of their unique business model. That entails using common technological and data infrastructure for the provision of different services. Notice, in that regard, that, particularly in western countries, the non-financial business lines of big techs are substantially larger than those related to regulated activities. Therefore, the grouping of all subsidiaries offering financial services under the same holding company may not be enough on its own to control operational risks or various forms of data and market abuse.
Furthermore, payment services are not explicitly included in the definition of FHCs in existing regulatory frameworks. Given the crucial role that payment services play within big tech ecosystems and, in particular, as an enabler for the provision of complementary financial services, a greater focus on payments could be added to the current FHC regime to enable it to achieve its objectives more fully when applied to large technological companies.
The FHC regime therefore seems a useful reference for a policy reflection on how best to regulate big techs with the aim of preserving financial stability and other relevant social goals. Yet that reflection should consider how the FHC regime could be adapted to cope with the unique business model of big techs and the key role played by their payment infrastructures.Concluding remarks
In that context, the public policy response to such a far-reaching technological disruption has to be commensurate with the magnitude of that disruption. That entails both direct public intervention to provide the required infrastructure to fully grasp the benefits associated with innovation as well as an overhaul of the current regulatory framework. The current regulatory setup, consisting of a series of diverse activity-based requirements accompanied by specific rules for traditional financial institutions, is simply not fit for purpose.
In particular, the potential implications of the activities performed by big techs in the market for financial services require the establishment of a consistent set of entity-based rules spanning different but related policy domains. For that purpose, we may need brand new regulatory categories and supervisory procedures to address the challenges posed by their unique business models, including effective mechanisms for coordination among financial, competition and data authorities.
The good news is of course that some relevant policy actions are already taking place in several jurisdictions. What we need now is sufficient ambition, policy impulse and international cooperation to make those efforts more comprehensive and consistent at the global level.Reference
Papers, no 905. November.
Auer, R, H Banka, N Yaa Boakye-Adjei, A Faragallah, J, H and J Prenio (BIS): “CBDCs and Financial Inclusion: Fixing a broken machine?” FSI Insights on Policy Implementation, forthcoming.
Bank for International Settlements (2020): “Big tech in finance: opportunities and risks”, Annual
Economic Report 2019, Chapter III.
Carstens, A (2021): “Public policy toward big techs in finance”, speech at the Asia School of Business Conversations on Central Banking webinar “Finance as information”, 27 January.
Carstens, A, S Claessens, F Restoy, and H S Shin (2021): “Regulating big techs in finance”, BIS
Bulletin, no 45.
Crisanto, J C, J Ehrentraud and M Fabian (2021): “Big techs in finance: regulatory approaches and
policy options”, FSI Briefs, no 12, March.
Crisanto, J C, J Ehrentraud, A Lawson and F Restoy (2021): “Big tech regulation: what is going on?”,
FSI Insights on policy implementation, no 36, September.
Crisanto, J C, J Ehrentraud, M Fabian and A Monteil: “Big tech interdependencies – a key regulatory blind spot?”, FSI Insights on Policy Implementation, forthcoming.
Croxson, K, J Frost, L Gambacorta and T Valletti (2022): “Platform-based business models and
financial inclusion”, BIS Working Papers, No 986, January.
D’Silva, D, Z Filková, F Packer and S Tiwari (2019): “The design of digital financial infrastructure: lessons from India”, BIS Papers, no 106, November.
Ehrentraud, J, J Evans, A Monteil and F Restoy: “How to regulate big techs”, FSI Occasional Papers, forthcoming.
Feyen, E, J Frost, L Gambacorta, H Natarajan and M Saal (2021): “A policy triangle for Big Techs in finance”, VoxEU, September.
编译 岑晓敏
编辑 刘嘉璐
来源 BIS
责编 李锦璇、蒋旭
监制 朱霜霜、董熙君
点击查看近期热文
欢迎加入群聊
为了增进与粉丝们的互动,IMI财经观察建立了微信交流群,欢迎大家参与。
入群方法:加群主为微信好友(微信号:imi605),添加时备注个人姓名(实名认证)、单位、职务等信息,经群主审核后,即可被拉进群。
欢迎读者朋友多多留言与我们交流互动,留言可换奖品:每月累积留言点赞数最多的读者将得到我们寄送的最新研究成果一份。
关于我们
中国人民大学国际货币研究所(IMI)成立于2009年12月20日,是专注于货币金融理论、政策与战略研究的非营利性学术研究机构和新型专业智库。研究所聘请了来自国内外科研院所、政府部门或金融机构的90余位著名专家学者担任顾问委员、学术委员和国际委员,80余位中青年专家担任研究员。
研究所长期聚焦国际金融、货币银行、宏观经济、金融监管、金融科技、地方金融等领域,定期举办国际货币论坛、货币金融(青年)圆桌会议、大金融思想沙龙、麦金农大讲坛、陶湘国际金融讲堂、IMF经济展望报告发布会、金融科技公开课等高层次系列论坛或讲座,形成了《人民币国际化报告》《天府金融指数报告》《金融机构国际化报告》《中国财富管理能力评价报告》《宏观经济月度分析报告》等一大批具有重要理论和政策影响力的学术成果。
2018年,研究所荣获中国人民大学优秀院属研究机构奖,在182家参评机构中排名第一;在《智库大数据报告(2018)》中获评A等级,在参评的1065个中国智库中排名前5%。2019年,入选智库头条号指数(前50名),成为第一象限28家智库之一。
国际货币网:http://www.imi.ruc.edu.cn
微信号:IMI财经观察
(点击识别下方二维码关注我们)
理事单位申请、
学术研究和会议合作
联系方式:
只分享最有价值的财经视点
We only share the most valuable financial insights.