查看原文
其他

IV回归系数比OLS大很多咋回事, 怎么办呢?

凡是搞计量经济的,都关注这个号了

箱:econometrics666@sina.cn

所有计量经济圈方法论丛的code程序, 宏微观数据库和各种软件都放在社群里.欢迎到计量经济圈社群交流访问.

上一日,咱们引荐了加权DID, IPW-DID实证程序百科全书式的宝典后面,咱们又引荐了一系列覆盖各种计量方法的文献综述 

2.机器学习和大数据计量经济学, 你必须阅读一下这篇

3.文本大数据分析在经济学和金融学中的应用, 最全文献综述

4.关于田野实验研究, 你不得不读的一篇综述文章

5.社科研究的文献综述的写作思路,主要针对P.h.d.学生的

6.计量化的公共管理领域研究,一篇全面的综述文章

7.中介效应分析的四种方式, 原则方法和应用综述

8.计量分析中的内生性问题综述,一篇不得不读的经典作品

这些都收到圈友们积极反响,原因在于里面有很多不得不读的经典著作。无论是中文,还是英文,都有很多经典文章需要好好研读,当然对于计量领域那可以多读读计量经济圈公众号。


计量经济圈社群日常


因果推断研究小组日常


看了计量经济圈社群的优质解答后,下面再读一读相关materials,一定会对你有较大帮助的。计量经济圈公众号里的很多内容可以直接通过菜单栏搜索到,在慢慢覆盖绝大部分应用微观实证领域的方法。


问题:IV估计的系数比OLS大了很多很多,有什么问题吗?


I am estimating an instrumental variable model by using -ivreg2 in Stata. The IV estimates are way more than OLS estimate (4.006567).Could you advise what could be possible reasons for such a blown up coeff (49.97424 )? or my interpretation of coeff is incorrect.

 

areg agr_share roaddum ims_hab_pop, robust absorb(dcode)

 

Woordbridge回答:

For the IV estimates to be at all convincing, first run the reduced form,

 

areg roaddum rank agr_share  ims_hab_pop, absorb(dcode) robust

 

and look at the sign of the coefficient on rank and its t statistic. Hopefully you have a predicted sign for the effect of rank on roaddum. If the sign is what you expect, is rank strongly statistically significant? The statistics for weak identification provide this information, too, but you should estimate the reduced form, anyway. It is easier to see what is happening.

 

伍德里奇怀疑有弱工具变量问题,又或者这个工具变量压根就不是外生的。

My guess is the instrument is weak. Or, the IV could actually be endogenous (which cannot be tested, unfortunately).



下面这个问题也是与此相关的,IV回归的系数相对于OLS很大的原因

I am doing an OLS analysis, and get a reasonable economic magnitude. I also do a 2sls analysis, still get significant results, but the economic magnitude is way above reasonable. Is there a justification for arguing that the 2sls confirms that the variables are indeed significant, but that we should not look at the economic magnitude of the 2sls, and instead, look at those of the OLS? Thanks


下面这个是非常细致的回答,尤其需要关注的是“局部平均处理效应”的异质性问题。

This is a good question, even though it got hounded on here. A couple of points.


First, the exclusion restriction for iV is untestable. Which is worth noting only because your IV estimate, which is significantly larger than your OLS estimate, is consistent so long as the instrument is exogenous, and that is an untestable assumption.


Second, it's entirely possible that the IV estimate to be larger than the OLS estimate because IV is estimating the local average treatment effect. Say that you are instrumenting for education and estimating the returns to schooling. OLS is estimating the average treatment effect (or trying to) over the entire population. What is IV estimating? It is estimating the local average treatment effect. So let's say that your instrument shifts the behavior of a subgroup of individuals for whom the returns to education are larger than average. Then IV estimates will be larger than OLS estimates because of heterogeneity in the population you're studying.


With that in mind, I will now somewhat contradict what I just said. This is basically where we are in the field, so you will have to probably defend those estimates against what I'm about to say.


You cannot prove the the instrument is excludable, sadly. But, the only known test of the exclusion restriction (which I already said doesn't exist) is a rule of thumb like what you're showing. Consider a simple diagram where you have Z as an instrument, X1 as the endogenous variable (schooling) and Y the outcome (salary). The exclusion restriction requires Z->X1 and X1->Y, but Z does not cause Y directly or through some other mediated variable, like X2.


If, though, Z->X2 and X2->Y, as well as Z->X1->Y, then you could have two biased estimates in OLS and 2SLS. There's a backdoor path from X1 to Y through X1<-Z->X2->Y. And when you estimate IV, you are estimating a first stage of X1 on Z, and a reduced form of Y on Z. And the IV estimator is the ratio of those two. But the reduced form model of YZ is biased as it may be that Z is causing Y through X2, which you've ruled out by assumption.


The IV estimate is going to be larger than OLS because the numerator>denominator in the IV model, which is Cov(Y,Z)/Cov(X1,Z). It's either that the numerator is blowing up, because there is a connection between Z and X1, or the first stage is weak. You probably checked whether the first stage is weak, so it's possible your untestable assumption is simply being violated.


This is hard because recall, it's entirely possible that LATE>ATE if there are heterogenous subpopulations. And in fact, the work of the last decade or so has focused a lot on that very possibility. Yet, when you have a blown up 2SLS coefficient compared to the OLS coefficient, I think people have a feeling that probably your instrument isn't exogenous in the first place.


继续追问:


Then what is the answer? OLS gives ATE. Under additional assumptions, IV gives LATE. How can the two be so wildly different? What does it mean? That the endogeneity is too hot to handle.


进一步用例子讲LATE:


Say you have two groups of workers, both uneducated. If group 1 goes to college, their wages increase by 10%. If group 2 goes to college their wages increase by 20%.


Now assume that the first group goes to college, and you estimate the ATT which would yield 10%.


Now assume that your instrument shifts the behavior of the second group only. Say that the second group was a discriminated minority, and that was the reason they didn't goto college. Now you shift them into college through some mandatory program, or hefty subsidies. As the first group was already going to college, your IV doesn't identify the ATT as your instrument is always only identifying the parameter associated with the behavior of the group affected by the instrument. So if you used IV, and it was valid, you'd estimate a 20% return to schooling.


But notice, that's only with regards to the affected sub-group. The ATT is 10% as noted. The LATE was twice as high, and that was only because the subgroup had such large returns.


I think that if you found something like this, you really will have your work cut out for you to defend it. There's a reason that Heckman says we typically care about the ATT moreso than the ATU (treatment effect on untreated). If you can't find it for the treatment group who self-select into treatment, then it's odd that you'd find an even larger effect for the untreated group. 


Economic theory would suggest the individuals with the highest returns to schooling are going to schooling, unless they face some different set of unobserved constraints or incentives -- say, liquidity constraints are different or discrimination is different. For certain applications, I think readers are probably primed to expect this -- like labor markets with discrimination -- but even then, there's a point of credibility one has to overcome since as I noted earlier the same large coefficients on 2SLS could be generated by an invalid instrument.


下面这些短链接文章属于合集,可以收藏起来阅读,不然以后都找不到了。

2年,计量经济圈公众号近1000篇文章,

Econometrics Circle

数据系列:空间矩阵 | 工企数据 | PM2.5 | 市场化指数 | CO2数据 |  夜间灯光 | 官员方言  | 微观数据

计量系列:匹配方法 | 内生性 | 工具变量 | DID | 面板数据 | 常用TOOL | 中介调节  | 时间序列 | RDD断点 | 合成控制 | 机器学习

数据处理:Stata | R | Python | 缺失值 | 

干货系列:能源环境 | 效率研究 | 空间计量 | 国际经贸 | 计量软件 | 商科研究 | 机器学习 | SSCI | CSSCI

计量经济圈组织了一个计量社群,有如下特征:热情互助最多、前沿趋势最多、社科资料最多、社科数据最多、科研牛人最多、海外名校最多。因此,建议积极进取和有强烈研习激情的中青年学者到社群交流探讨,始终坚信优秀是通过感染优秀而互相成就彼此的。

: . Video Mini Program Like ,轻点两下取消赞 Wow ,轻点两下取消在看

您可能也对以下帖子感兴趣

文章有问题?点此查看未经处理的缓存